As green energy costs drop, we should shift the emphasis
from economy-wide carbon pricing to sectoral policies
World leaders have accepted the warnings of scientists that global
temperatures must increase by no more than 1.5 or 2 degrees Celsius to
avoid severe damage to the Earth’s ecosystems and to human health and
welfare. According to recent surveys, the general public increasingly
agrees on the need for climate action.
As a result, many countries and some subnational entities have set
ambitious targets for reducing greenhouse gas emissions. This past spring,
the United Kingdom adopted a target of 78 percent emissions reductions by
2035, relative to 1990 levels. In the United States, the Biden
administration announced a (nonbinding) goal of reducing net greenhouse gas
emissions by 50–52 percent by 2030, relative to 2005. At the subnational
level, several US states, including California, Colorado, Massachusetts,
and New York, have legislated targets to approach or reach net zero
emissions by 2050.
The climate crisis is too important to let these goals turn into failed
promises. What policies are needed to turn these ambitious targets into
action?
Economists’ standard prescription is to implement a robust economy-wide
price on carbon. A carbon price that starts at a moderate rate and grows
predictably will incentivize individuals to use lower-carbon sources of
energy than fossil fuels and will induce firms and power generators to
switch away from fossil fuels to low-carbon primary sources of energy. An
economy-wide carbon price efficiently obtains emissions reductions from
sectors or uses where they are least costly while keeping costs manageable
in applications difficult to decarbonize. Moreover, depending on how it is
implemented, revenues from a carbon price can be used to reduce
distortionary taxes elsewhere or to provide needed public investment.
A frequent response to this prescription is that it ignores the political
reality that carbon pricing, especially through a carbon tax, is unpopular.
Despite considerable efforts over decades, only a small fraction of
worldwide carbon emissions is covered by a carbon pricing program, and
among those programs that do exist, the carbon price is typically low.
Now there is an additional reason to question this focus on economy-wide
carbon pricing: it was developed when green energy was expected to remain
far more expensive than fossil fuels. In many parts of the world, however,
green energy, especially wind- and solar-generated power, is either less
expensive than fossil fuel generation or is likely to become so soon. Costs
of technologies to use green electricity—electric vehicles, for
example—have also fallen dramatically. How does climate policy advice
change for a world where it could be cheaper to be green?
Three externalities
Policies for the energy transition confront (at least) three externalities:
the greenhouse gas externality; the innovation externality; and, in some
cases, network (or chicken-and-egg) externalities. The greenhouse gas
externality arises because the cost of damages to others, now and in the
future, is not borne by those who burn fossil fuels. The innovation
externality arises because the financial gains from innovation generally
cannot be fully appropriated by the innovator. This externality justifies
public financial support for basic research but also extends to other
aspects of innovation, such as non-appropriable learning by doing in
production and management. In the context of the energy transition, the
network externality typically stems from built infrastructure. An example
is electric vehicles (EVs) and charging stations: a lack of charging
stations holds back demand for EVs, but a lack of these vehicles holds back
the private supply of charging stations. In this case, there can be two
stable equilibria: one with few EVs and charging stations and one with many
EVs and charging stations.
Environmental economists have historically focused on the greenhouse gas
externality, and with good reason: for the past hundred years, it has been
significantly cheaper to emit carbon dioxide than not to when producing and
using energy. When that is the case, the goal of climate policy is to
encourage efficient self-restraint through policies such as carbon pricing
and energy efficiency standards and to encourage changes in behavior, such
as flying and driving less.
But two things have changed. First, the cost of producing clean
electricity by wind and solar power has fallen dramatically, to the point
that, in some parts of the United States, building new grid-scale solar and
wind systems is less expensive than running existing coal and
natural-gas-fired generators. Second, for some applications the cost of using clean energy may soon be lower than that of using fossil
fuels, although this varies a good deal depending on the sector.
Making it cheaper to be green
The prospect of cheap green energy requires a fundamental shift in how we
think about climate policy—from how we can make it more expensive to be
dirty to how we can make it cheaper to be green. Whether we actually reach
a low-cost green equilibrium is far from certain, however: whether we get
there, and how quickly, hinges on policy.
With multiple market failures, efficient policy needs multiple policy
instruments. Because all sectors and all countries are different, there is
no single elegant one-size-fits-all combination of instruments. Rather, the
most efficient suite of policies for one sector is generally not the most
efficient suite for other sectors. An efficient mix of climate policy
instruments must be crafted to address market failures, technological
status, and institutional challenges at a more nuanced level.
Consider, for example, light- and medium-duty vehicles. The price of a new
EV is on track to fall below that of comparable conventional internal
combustion engine vehicles during this decade. This price decline is driven
by the ongoing, remarkable decline in battery prices, manufacturers’
increasing experience in producing EVs, and improved battery technologies
on the horizon. Moreover, EVs are less expensive to operate and maintain
than conventional vehicles.
But the transition to EVs is not a sure thing, and in any event it can be expedited and supported by policy. In particular,
the chicken-and-egg externality of charging stations poses some significant challenges. Absent
adequate slow (level 2) charging stations, EV owners must provide their own
charging capacity—which means a dedicated parking space where they are able
to install a charger. Not surprisingly, EV purchases heavily skew toward
higher-income families with their own garages, which in turn affects the
types of EVs produced. Policy to support reliable widespread overnight or
at-work charger availability could help overcome this chicken-and-egg
problem, thereby accelerating the transition and ensuring a larger EV
share.
On the other hand, a moderate carbon tax is likely to have little effect on
EV purchases, because the cost impact is small (a $40/ton carbon tax
implies $0.36 for a gallon of gasoline). In fact, there is a substantial
literature that investigates whether car buyers properly take into account
fuel prices when they purchase a vehicle; that literature tends to find
that purchasers only partially account for fuel prices. For light- and
medium-duty vehicles, addressing the network externalities and innovation
externalities for advanced batteries is more effective and impactful than
carbon pricing. Because those policies aim to facilitate the transition
from the current low-EV equilibrium to a stable, low-cost high-EV
equilibrium, those transitional policies have a limited duration and
one-time costs.
In contrast, aviation is a major and growing source of carbon dioxide
emissions and appears quite difficult to decarbonize. Currently there is
enthusiasm about low-carbon sustainable aviation fuel. Such fuel can be
produced through conventional pathways such as conversion of waste
vegetable oils and oil crops to renewable jet fuel or through advanced
pathways—for example low- or negative-carbon alcohols, such as ethanol from
energy grasses, converted to jet fuel.
In its 2021 Annual Energy Outlook, however, the US Energy
Information Administration projected the price of petroleum jet fuel to be
$2.77/gallon in 2050 (2020 US dollars). The prospect of sustainable
aviation fuel competing with petroleum jet fuel at $2.77/gallon, unaided by
an implicit or explicit carbon price, is daunting. A switch to sustainable
fuel depends on robust funding to address the innovation externality and,
when those fuels become available at scale, a high carbon price (either an
explicit price or a clean fuel standard for aviation). Especially if the
carbon price is implemented through an aviation fuel standard, this phasing
could be critical: implementing a fuel standard too soon runs the risk of
preferencing first-generation fuels without adequate support for scalable
fuels with zero or negative carbon footprints, as has been seen in the
failure of the US Renewable Fuel Standard to promote second-generation
low-carbon ethanol. Sustainable aviation fuel works in standard jet engines
and uses much the same infrastructure as petroleum jet fuel, so network
externalities matter less. For aviation, this suggests policy that strongly
supports the development and commercialization of advanced, scalable, and
truly low-carbon sustainable aviation fuel now and a credible commitment to
a high sectoral carbon price in the future.
In the power sector, all three externalities figure prominently in the
transition. In the United States, new wind and solar power generation is
less expensive than coal and natural gas in some but not all parts of the
country. As a result, US power sector modeling suggests that a national
policy that effectively puts a price on carbon—such as a clean electricity
standard—is necessary to achieve substantial near-term decarbonization, say
80 percent by 2030. Deeper decarbonization will likely require significant
innovation-driven cost reductions in storage technologies. In addition, the
infrastructure of the US power sector restricts the ability to transmit
green electricity from regions with high renewable resources to demand
centers.
The power sector also faces serious institutional challenges, such as the
regulatory and physical ability to use time-of-day pricing and load
management and the institutional and political problems of siting new
transmission capacity. For the power sector, supporting research and
development of long-term storage technologies and addressing multiple
infrastructure and institutional limitations are essential. The necessary
first step, however, is a sectoral policy, such as a clean electricity
standard, that has the effect of placing a price on carbon.
This is not to say that an economy-wide carbon tax is undesirable: the
decarbonization from a clean electricity standard, and its limited effect
on power prices, could be accomplished by an economy-wide carbon tax
combined with government subsidies for renewable power, and that tax would
yield some decarbonization from other sectors as well. For aviation, an
economy-wide carbon price could, two decades from now, support the use of
still-expensive low- or zero-carbon alternatives to petroleum jet fuel. But
this reasoning suggests that pursuing an economy-wide carbon price is a
lower priority today than it was when it was expensive to be green.
Economy-wide carbon pricing, while desirable, by itself is neither
efficient nor, at politically plausible prices, sufficient to drive deep
decarbonization.
How can economists help?
I have focused on the economic case for shifting from economy-wide pricing
to sectoral policies. That case is strengthened by the evident aversion of
the political system to explicit pricing. But the political benefit of
sectoral policies—their less visible costs than economy-wide pricing, in
part because nonexperts often do not fully understand them—also exposes
them to inefficiencies. Given the scale of the decarbonization challenge,
it is critical that such policies be as cost-effective as possible. We
cannot afford to spend trillions of dollars on policies that fail to
achieve deep decarbonization.
Given the scale of the challenge,
it is critical that such policies be as cost-effective as possible.
Sectoral climate policy design questions are often nuanced. How can a
charging station policy be designed to maximize electric vehicle adoption
and use instead of simply providing inframarginal transfers for stations
that would be built anyway? Is investing in green industrial policy—for
example, subsidizing domestic battery production—a cost-effective way to
reduce emissions in the long run? Are subsidies for purchasing electric
vehicles likely to be passed through to the consumer and thereby stimulate
sales? What policies will most efficiently support the robust development
of low-carbon sustainable aviation fuels?
Economists are good at disentangling incentives, anticipating unintended
consequences, and assessing the costs and benefits of candidate policies.
One practical challenge for economists working on sectoral policies is that
those policies can become highly detailed; another is that policy is
evolving on a time scale faster than that of academic economists. This is
where the world’s economic policy institutions, like the IMF, can play a
critical role by enhancing and providing nuanced, sectoral expertise to
promote the transition to a greener—and in many cases, cheaper—energy
future.
Opinions expressed in articles and other materials are those of the authors; they do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF and its Executive Board, or IMF policy.